Tag Archives: manager

The Confounding Bias For Investment Complexity

“Simplicity is a great virtue but it requires hard work to achieve it and education to appreciate it. And to make matters worse: complexity sells better.” – Edsger W. Dijkstra 1 Our tenure in the investment business has made us keenly aware of a profound investor bias toward complexity. In this article, we examine the reasons for the bias, which we believe are behavioral in nature. One reason is the rationalization by asset managers that to charge higher fees requires offering more complex strategies. A similar line of reasoning may also influence those who recommend managers: consultants and advisors. A second reason for the bias is the rationalization by investors that a complicated strategy is necessary to beat the market. Each explanation has implications-biased toward the negative-for an investor’s long-term performance. Complexity Can Confound Performance In contrast to the overwhelming pressure from all sides in advancing complexity, our experience, as well as our research and that of others, supports the virtues of a simple approach. For example, in 2009, DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal demonstrated that numerically optimized portfolios using various expected return models generally perform no better than a simple equal-weighted approach. An example of our research in this area, the article “A Survey of Alternative Equity Index Strategies” by Chow et al. (2011), is an analysis of the most popular smart beta strategies. We found that simple, low-turnover and complex, high-turnover strategies all work roughly the same on a gross-of-fee basis, suggesting on a net-of-fee basis the simple, low-turnover strategies might have an advantage. Looking beyond the story telling that characterizes various investment philosophies, the long-term return drivers of many complex smart beta strategies are tilts toward well-known factor/style exposures, such as value, size, and low volatility. Each exposure is a natural outcome of breaking the link between portfolio weighting and price, and of the requisite rebalancing. Indeed, little data or research supports one “best” way to construct an exposure (e.g., value or low volatility) that maximizes the factor premium capture. Complex constructions in the historical backtest appear to mostly guarantee higher turnover, higher management fees, and potentially worse out-of-sample returns. So, if complexity doesn’t naturally lead to outperformance, why do asset managers persist in offering increasingly complicated strategies to investors, and why do investors persist on investing in them? Allow John to tell an illustrative parable. John’s Fish Tale The oceans in which fish hide from fisherman are amazingly complex ecosystems. The circumstances leading to a successful day (or not) on the water are almost innumerable. The fish obviously have to be at the fishing spot. But that’s probably less than half the battle. A veritable mosaic of tides, currents, sunlight, moonlight the night before, available prey, time of day, tackle, and so on, influence the catch. With such a myriad of factors, it’s no small wonder that tens of thousands of fishing products jam their way into even the smallest of tackle shops. But, as an avid deep sea angler, I can attest to catching twice as many tuna with the simplest of lures than all of the rest combined. The lure? The innocuous-looking cedar plug pictured in Exhibit A . Simple? Yes! For crying out loud, it’s a piece of lead attached to an unpainted piece of wood with one lousy hook! It looks like an industrial part. Sexy and complex? Most certainly not. Imagine you get the itch to catch some tuna. Perhaps it’s your first foray into tuna fishing so you decide to delegate the task to an expert charter boat captain. But which one? You stroll along the dock and ask each captain how they catch tuna. The first presents a cedar plug, just like the one in Exhibit A, and tells you, “I go out to where I see signs of fish and then I drag four of these lures behind the boat at a steady speed until I catch some. Then I keep doing it until it’s time to head in.” The second captain displays a dozen tackle drawers filled with lures resembling those shown in Exhibit B and proclaims, “Tuna are very elusive. I have perfected a system over many years that optimizes my lure selection among 60 lures, five sunlight conditions, seven moon phases, and six different tidal stages. I troll, adjusting my speed in five-minute intervals, based again on very extensive testing.” You hate long boat rides, but are starving for fresh sashimi. Which captain would you choose? Most sashimi lovers would pick the second captain. The ocean is big, and multiple factors influence the tuna catch. It seems like the higher-calibrated approach would be the way to go. But I can tell you (admittedly anecdotally, as I’m still waiting for Research Affiliates to approve my request for a more exhaustive scientific survey!) that it would probably yield a lower catch. Investors’ Preference for Complexity Complexity likewise appeals to investors because the markets that drive securities prices, like the teeming and mysterious ocean, are deep and complex. It only stands to reason (right?) that a sophisticated strategy is a requirement for mastering and benefiting from the intricate web of financial markets and asset classes. The globally integrated investment markets and economies are anything but simple, so it would not at first appear that a simple strategy could carry the day. The belief that simple relationships exist is absolutely counterintuitive to most casual-and sometimes, not so casual-market observers. Persuading an investor that a complicated strategy-often derived through data mining (i.e., back testing historical data until it produces what can be viewed as a signal)-is unlikely to perform as expected, can be a real challenge. The air of scientific authority exuded by PhDs who scribble differential calculus equations as fast as Charles Schultz drew Peanuts comic strips gives just that much more “credibility” to black box approaches. And agents compound the issue. Advisors or consultants hired to help investors make sense of the noise in the market and to find the skilled managers are also incented by the complex. Charging a respectable fee for a manager selection process that puts the client into a simple, straightforward strategy is not so easily justified to the client. The very natural, economic, and rational response to this conundrum is to recommend (in the case of advisors) or to offer (in the case of managers) the more complex strategies. Asset managers certainly find it easier to charge a higher fee for a complex strategy (i.e., flashier lures with molded plastic and psychedelic paints) than for a simple strategy (i.e., unpainted cedar plugs). Simplicity vs. Complexity: Why Does It Matter? The point we wish to make is not that simple strategies always perform on par or better than the complex ones. Our point is that complexity creates a problem for investors, which is unfortunately largely self-induced: complexity encourages performance chasing. We can better understand why this is true if we apply Daniel Kahneman’s construct of System 1 and System 2 thinking, as described in his book Thinking, Fast and Slow (2011). System 1 thinking is described as automatic, emotional, and passive, whereas System 2 thinking is effortful, deliberate, and active. When presented with a complicated investment strategy, an investor engages first in System 1 thinking, which triggers an immediate response such as “I don’t understand the strategy. Clearly I’m not as smart as this asset manager.” System 2 thinking then takes over, and the investor’s response transitions to “Because this asset manager is so smart, her strategy must outperform. I think I’d like to invest with this asset manager.” The investor then feels safe and comfortable in making a rational delegation decision. At the end of the day, the acceptance of complexity is related to calming the investor’s ego-at least, temporarily. This thinking works in reverse, however, if the asset manager fails to perform as expected. Neuroscientists, such as Knutson and Peterson (2004), have demonstrated that the anticipation of receiving money triggers a dopamine reward in the brain. Conversely, the anticipation of losing money removes that pleasurable experience. When this happens, the System 1 response is “Yikes! I need to fire this manager so I can stop feeling so bad.” Then the System 2 response kicks in with the rationalization, “I didn’t make the decisions that created the underperformance, so I’m not to blame.” Because the investor doesn’t “own” making the “bad” decisions, it is easier to end the relationship. Following this line of thinking, investors are liable to sell a complicated, poorly understood strategy with little provocation as soon as performance takes a nose dive. The long-term result is apt to be especially disappointing performance if the investor becomes ensnared in a whipsaw pattern of buying and selling at all the wrong times. Our research (Hsu, Myers, and Whitby [2015]) shows that the frequent hiring and firing of managers based on short-term performance is the primary cause of investor underperformance. Our findings are valid even when investors hire skilled managers. Although never a good idea for investors to make buy and sell decisions based on short-term performance, a poorly understood strategy can compound the harm. An example of how Kahneman’s System 1 and 2 thinking supports an investor’s choice of a simple behavioral factor strategy, let’s consider the following scenario. Upon first encountering the strategy, the investor’s System 1 thinking blurts, “This strategy is intuitive to me. I am a smart investment professional. This will work.” But soon his System 2 thinking chimes in, “I don’t need to pay a high fee for this. I just need a low-cost implementer of systematic strategies to execute on my chosen factor.” When the strategy fails to perform as expected, the investor’s System 1 reaction is, “I am not wrong. The market is wrong.” Then his System 2 thinking kicks in, reasoning, “I vetted the research behind this factor carefully. Short-term performance is noisy. This exposure will work well in the long run.” The investor chooses to hold his strategy. Investors in simple strategies generally trade in and out of their managers infrequently. Our research finds that these investors tend to achieve meaningfully better results versus their counterparts who actively turn over managers due to recent performance. Simplicity leads to better investor outcomes not because simplicity in and of itself produces better investment returns, but because a simple strategy forces investors to own their decisions and to be less likely to overreact to short-term noise. A Simple Choice We believe that making investors aware of the benefits of selecting a simple approach, strategy, or model is important. Unnecessary complexity is costly, not only directly (i.e., fees), but indirectly. Complexity can dampen investor understanding, which can lead to poor investment decision making so that an investor’s long-term financial goals are not achieved. As Steve Jobs said, “Some people think design means how it looks. But of course, if you dig deeper, it’s really how it works” (Wolf, 1996). If a simple design works, ample evidence suggests that the investor benefits by choosing simplicity. Endnote 1. Edsger W. Dijkstra was a Dutch computer scientist and winner of the Turing Prize in 1972 for fundamental contributions to developing programming languages. References Chow, Tzee Mann, Jason Hsu, Vitali Kalesnik, and Bryce Little. 2011. ” A Survey of Alternative Equity Index Strategies .” Financial Analysts Journal , vol. 67, no. 5 (September/October):37-57. DeMiguel, Victor, Lorenzo Garlappi, and Raman Uppal. 2009. “Optimal Versus Naïve Diversification: How Inefficient Is the 1/N Portfolio Strategy?” Review of Financial Studies , vol. 22, no. 5 (May):1915-1953. Hsu, Jason, Brett Myers, and Brian Whitby. Forthcoming 2016. ” Timing Poorly: A Guide to Generating Poor Returns While Investing in Successful Strategies .” Journal of Portfolio Management , vol. 42, no. 2 (Winter). Kahneman, Daniel. 2011. Thinking, Fast and Slow . New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux. Knutson, Brian, and Richard Peterson. 2005. “Neurally Reconstructing Expected Utility.” Games and Economic Behavior , vol. 52, no. 2 (August):305-315. Wolf, Gary. 1996. ” Steve Jobs: The Next Insanely Great Thing .” Wired Magazine (February)

Revisiting A Paradigm Shift: Allocation Decisions In The Absence Of Theory

Problems with CAPM and EMH suggest that Modern Portfolio Theory is not useful for individual investors. As a result, modern finance is in the midst of a paradigm shift similar to those discussed by Kuhn (1962). On an interim basis, using James Montier’s trinity of risk plus behavioral finance as an overlay may work. James Montier, the famous value investor now at GMO Asset Management, has written extensively about the huge contradictions between academic theory and real world observations when it comes to the dynamic between risk and reward in the markets. This is a topic I have been interested in for a long time, because the disjunction between theory and practice should (but usually doesn’t) strongly affect how investment managers view risk and construct client portfolios. Montier began his argument with a review of the evolution of market theory, and especially that part of theory called the Capital Asset Pricing Model, or CAPM. In the 1950’s future Nobel Laureate Harry Markowitz wrote his Ph.D. thesis on a mathematical model for asset allocation called portfolio optimization. His model could theoretically be used to construct portfolios that combined maximum gain with minimum risk for any investor whose assets were diversified. Eventually this approach led, in conjunction with the CAPM, to what is now called Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT). Many institutions today use a modified version of MPT to develop their recommended asset allocations. The CAPM part of modern theory was introduced by Nobel Laureate William Sharpe and his colleagues in the 1960’s. In brief, the CAPM assumed that all investors would use Markowitz’s optimization method, so that a single mathematical factor could be isolated that would distinguish between stocks of differing risk levels, and that factor is called beta (i.e., beta is that part of a stock’s risk that can be attributed to market fluctuations that are systematic and undiversifiable, and this in turn depends in part on a stock’s correlation to the market, as represented by the S & P 500). The final component of MPT was the development of a concept called the Efficient Market Hypothesis by Nobel Laureate Eugene Fama. As part of his work Fama attempted to prove that information is equally available to all players in the markets, so therefore the markets are efficient and all stocks are correctly priced. Over time this idea led directly to the notion that the best investment approach is to use passive indexes to fill out a portfolio allocation, since no one should expect to beat efficient markets for any substantial period of time. It is important to note that this idea of efficient markets is really just an assumption used to make mathematical treatment possible. There is abundant evidence that the assumption of market efficiency is false, as has been discussed by Warren Buffett, John Mauldin and many others. One only needs to think back to the NASDAQ bubble in the late 1990’s and its subsequent collapse, or the carnage of the Great Financial Crisis in 2008, to find glaring examples of inefficient markets. A basic tenet of CAPM is that risk and reward are directly proportional. This means that as risk increases, so does reward. However, a study in the late 2000s by JPMorgan has shown just the opposite trend for real world data. In other words, when 20 years of actual market (the Russell indexes) data through 2008 were plotted, they indicated a strong linear relationship between risk and reward all right, but it was reciprocal. Thus, if risk increases in the real markets, reward can actually decrease. Indeed, Fama and his long-time colleague French published a paper in 2004 showing that for the period from 1923 to 2003, using all stocks on the NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ, the highest risk (highest beta) stocks considerably underperformed relative to the predictions of the CAPM. The reverse was also true, in that the lowest risk (lowest beta) stocks considerably outperformed relative to the predictions of the CAPM. Over the long run, there was essentially no relationship between beta and stock returns. Yet another study was conducted a few years ago by Jeremy Grantham of GMO Asset Management, who found that for the 600 largest U.S. stocks (for the time period from 1963 to 2006), those with the lowest beta have had the highest returns. Montier himself has studied the risk-return relationship for European stocks for the period from 1986 to 2006 as well, with essentially the same result. Montier’s explanation for the failure of the CAPM over shorter time frames is based on the many questionable assumptions that have to be made for the model to “work” mathematically. Amongst the more questionable assumptions are: 1) no taxes are paid, so investors are indifferent between dividends and capital gains; 2) all investors use Markowitz portfolio optimization at all times; and 3) investors can take any position (long or short) without affecting the market price. These assumptions are implicitly accepted by all who use MPT and CAPM to manage portfolios, such as many institutional asset managers. These may indeed be valid over very long time frames, but then they may not be appropriate for mere mortals to use with their personal investments. This assumed validity reaches its ultimate level of absurdity in the obsession many financial institutions have for so-called short term “tracking error”. Tracking error measures the variability in the difference between a fund manager’s portfolio returns and the returns of the appropriate stock index. Many institutional managers have been compensated on the basis of tracking error. Thus, the variance in investor portfolio returns has not always been considered; rather, a manager’s relative performance against an index is the criterion by which they are commonly judged. This means that if the market loses 20% in a given year and the manager only loses 18%, that manager may very well bonus for outperformance on a tracking error basis, even though their clients lost significant money. Modern hedge funds are in part the profession’s response to client angst over this state of affairs. Many hedge funds attempt to provide steady absolute returns, and that is why they have become so popular amongst high net worth clients. Unfortunately, retail clients until recently had no sophisticated risk-control strategies available to them, but that is changing. If you accept for the purposes of argument that both CAPM and the Efficient Markets Hypothesis are invalid or at least suspect, then you are presented with a dilemma. MPT doesn’t really work except during 50 year periods and longer, which is way too long for use with retail clients, but it is the only theory with any mathematical rigor that is widely accepted. This situation is reminiscent of the problems faced in the physical sciences when an old foundational theory or paradigm has been tossed out, but a new one has not yet appeared. The classic examples are the paradigm shift that occurred when Newton proposed his gravitational theory, and again when Einstein proposed his theories about relativity. This problem was written about brilliantly by Thomas S. Kuhn in his book on “The Structure of Scientific Revolutions,” published in 1962. What generally happens is that the old guard defends the old paradigm even while it is being destroyed as an explanatory tool by new data, so that only younger scientists like Newton and Einstein can break through to new paradigms, and then only when the old guard stops fighting. A famous quote on the matter is attributed to the physicist Max Planck in the early 1900s: “Science progresses one funeral at a time.” I believe, as do others, that this is where we now find ourselves with respect to MPT. Grad schools still teach it, but applying it during the sequential bubbles of the last 20 years has yielded awful results on a risk-adjusted basis. Over an even longer period, since 1982, 30-year zero coupon bonds have beaten the S & P 500 by an absolutely huge margin, as Gary Shilling has been pointing out for many years. The careful practitioner then has a dilemma, assuming that he or she now rejects the old MPT paradigm: there is no mathematically rigorous new paradigm to replace it with. How do we go about asset allocation then? Many others have explored this question in recent years, but with a possible new bear market ahead of us sometime in 2016 or 2017, there is renewed urgency to the quest for answers. Behavioral finance has provided a rich and powerful explanation for what happens in the real world of the markets. It should be a major part of the equation, and goes a long way towards explaining the problems with MPT, but it is not inherently mathematical itself. I am reconciled to thinking that since human beings are involved in economics and markets, there will be no mathematical solution. I personally have been using Montier’s “trinity of risk” concept as a template for making allocation decisions. His trinity consists of valuation risk, business/earnings risk, and balance sheet/financial risk. These can be applied in some way to most asset classes. But a behavioral finance overlay can be useful as well. It is on this basis that I have written elsewhere that I strongly favor certain bonds over stocks, and possibly even over cash, in 2016. The most important conclusion for investors to draw from this discussion is that the assumptions that underlie an asset manager’s approach should be examined carefully and judged for their conformity with that investor’s investment goals. Most will reject the notion that periodic 50% losses are acceptable, so a more risk-aware approach is needed. I realize that I have not really answered all of the questions I have posed; clearly this is a work in progress.